ag-geldordnung-und-finanzpolitik AT lists.piratenpartei.de
Betreff: Kommunikationsmedium der bundesweiten AG Geldordnung und Finanzpolitik
Listenarchiv
- From: moneymind <moneymind AT gmx.de>
- To: ag-geldordnung-und-finanzpolitik AT lists.piratenpartei.de
- Subject: [AG-GOuFP] der (vorerst) verlorene Kampf um die Finanztransaktionssteuer
- Date: Fri, 08 Aug 2014 22:49:29 +0000
- List-archive: <https://service.piratenpartei.de/pipermail/ag-geldordnung-und-finanzpolitik>
- List-id: Kommunikationsmedium der bundesweiten AG Geldordnung und Finanzpolitik <ag-geldordnung-und-finanzpolitik.lists.piratenpartei.de>
Schulmeister hat eine hervorragende Analyse des Streits um die Finanztransaktionssteuer seit 2008ff. veröffentlicht.
Ich stelle den Anfang mal hier rein (Hervorhebungen von mir), Link zum Rest am Ende:
*Abstract *
The struggle over the FTT has developed in three phases. In the first phase (2009 to 2011) the supporters of the tax went on the offensive, supported by the "shock effects" of the financial crisis. This phase ended with the (preliminary) "victory" in the form of the FTT proposal of the European Commission in September 2011. The second phase was shaped by the search for ways how to implement the FTT within the EU. It ended with the publication of a modified FTT proposal by the Commission in February 2013 as basis for the implementation in 11 member countries. The last phase has been marked by a strong counter-offensive of the financial lobby which succeeded in playing off FTT supporting countries against each other, in particular Germany and France. This phase ended with a defeat of the FTT supporters.
Not even in a group of EU countries will a general FTT be implemented in the foreseeable future.
The struggle over the FTT was mainly carried out in two "battlefields", the intellectual disputes between economists at universities, research institutes and international organisations, and the political controversies between NGOs, political parties, governments and pressure groups, in particular the finance industry.
/
The conflict between recognition and interest, explanation and justification, analytical and normative thinking shapes the work of economists to a much larger extent than the work of any other types of intellectuals. The reason is given by Keynes at the end of his “General Theory”: “......the ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and when they are wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood. Indeed the world is ruled by little else.” (Keynes, 1936, p. 383). /
*/
If economic theories “rule the world” then the distribution of power, income and wealth depends on which economic theory becomes a “paradigm”. This is so because economists then derive from this “Weltanschauung” the “navigation map” for policy. The thinking of economists is therefore driven by the interaction of three forces/motives/activities: Analysis and recognition of “true” relationships (science), justification of interests (ideology), and elaboration of concepts for “improving the world” (ethics). /*Any output of economists’ reasoning is a “mixture” resulting from the interaction of these three activities.
Even though one cannot exactly quantify the contribution of each of these activities (as they are closely interlinked), the following rule of thumb helps to gauge the importance of the ideological component of an economic theory or proposal: The higher is the degree of abstraction of their model, and the less its basic assumptions are derived from empirical research/experience, the more plausible is the suspicion that assumptions as well as methods were chosen to arrive at certain conclusions.
*/Classical economists, notably Adam Smith, David Ricardo and Karl Marx, were well aware of the conflicting economic and political interests of different classes in society. As a consequence, they embedded their theories in the context of the interaction of these interests./* Conceiving themselves as members of the society, those economists took clear positions in favour of certain classes and against other classes. Their economics was devoted to analysing the “*political economy*” and to formulate proposals for its improvement - the idea of a “value-free” economic science would have seemed absurd to the classics.
Related to this understanding is their methodological approach: As they try to explain the most important economic developments like economic growth, specialization and trade, the distribution of income and wealth, the role of government in a market economy, etc., they try to base their assumptions on observations and to reach general conclusions carefully in an inductive way (taking into account the historical and regional context).
Even though the content of the - genuinely macroeconomic - theory of Keynes is very different from the – market-oriented - classical theories, Keynes shared the attitude of the classics in many respects: Also Keynes thought concretely and problem-oriented, based his reasoning rather on experience than on abstract models, and as a “political philosopher” he put his theory in the context of the conflict of interests of entrepreneurs, workers and(financial) rentiers. Last but not least, Keynes elaborated many concrete proposals for a better organization of the domestic and for the global economy. In complete contrast to this attitude, neoclassical economics, which has become the predominant school since the late 19th century, assumes that there exist “eternal truths” about the functioning of a capitalistic market economy. Economics is conceived as a value-free science, which aims at finding out these “economic laws” (they are assumed to be valid beyond time and space). */Establishing economics as a value-free and, hence, nonideological science is itself the most important ideological component of the neoclassical school of thought. Such a self-image enables economists to “sell” their conclusions as objective truths and to repress the simple question: Which groups/classes are favoured or put at a disadvantage by the neoclassical “truths”. /*
The denial of the interaction between economic theory and economic reality calls for a specific methodological approach: One sets assumptions about the agents (“homo oeconomicus”), ideal market conditions, permanent market clearing, etc., all of which are not supported by the empirical evidence. Based on these assumptions, one constructs highly abstract models from which those results are (tauto)logically deducted which are already contained in the assumptions: All markets should be “liberalized”, governments should refrain from an active economic policy, irrespective whether it regards business cycle fluctuations, social security, income distribution or the regulations of the financial sector, etc. All these prescriptions favour certain groups in society over others. I term the first – classical and original Keynesian - approach to analysing economic relationships “realistic economics” (RE) and the neoclassical approach “idealistic economics” (IE). The key differences between both approaches concerns the way of thinking:
“Realistic economics” (RE) addresses concrete economic problems, collects empirical observations and tries to arrive at general conclusions about the relevant relationships in a predominantly – yet not exclusively – inductive manner. RE acknowledges the importance of contradictions in the economy,which should therefore be incorporated in economic theory. Policy recommendations are problem-oriented, pragmatic and, hence, embedded in the context of historical time. “Idealistic economics” (IE) aimsat modelling the universe of economic relationships in an ideal world – free of contradictions. To this end, IE has to make assumptions which “abstract away” essential properties of human beings and of their interaction in society like the role of emotions or of uncertainty.
From the general equilibrium models based on these assumptions, onededucts a “navigation map” for economic policy – again valid beyond time and space. The two different approaches to economics do not only shape the activities of economists at the academic level, but also economic policy. E. g., the New Deal of Roosevelt or the full employment policy of the 1950s and 1960s are typical examples of the RE approach, strict rules for monetary and fiscal policy like the fiscal compact of the EU or deregulation as a general guideline are typical for the IE approach. The sequence of prosperity and depressions is interconnected with the sequence of RE and IE paradigms. One specific reason for that lies in the influence of economic paradigms on the incentive conditions of the overall system. IE paradigms favour deregulation in general and of financial markets in particular so that striving for profits shifts gradually from the real to the financial economy. The “production” of “fictitious capital” (Karl Marx) in the form of overvalued assets, in particular the government debt, leads inevitably into a deep crisis. After a long lasting learning period (the bottom phase of the “long cycle”), an RE paradigm leads to changes in the incentive structure and in economic policy: Striving for profits is again focused on activities in the real economy, leading to prosperity. The long cycle since the 1920s is a good example for this interaction: The finance-capitalistic framework conditions and the related stock market boom led to the crash of 1929, the subsequent recession was transformed into a depression due to the austerity policy prescribed by the IE paradigm. The learning from the crisis, in particular in the form of a new RE theory provided by Keynes, laid the ground for the real-capitalistic system of the 1950s and 1960s. Since then, the restoration of the neoclassic paradigm, completed by the most unrealistic assumptions ever made in the history of economic thought (rational expectations, financial market efficiency, real business cycle, etc.), served as the scientific legitimation of the interest of finance capital in a complete deregulation of asset markets. The related change in the incentive conditions paved the long way into the current crisis.
At present, the European economy is in a state of depression (external demand is the only growth component), typical for the bottom phase of the long cycle: The IE recipes continue to weaken domestic demand, yet, the elites re main stuck in the neoliberal paradigm which has been dominating longer than ever before.
In such a situation where a new RE paradigm is not in sight, single RE proposals are put forward which could/should change the course of events (e. g., the Glass-Steagall act of 1933 to restrict - as Roosevelt put it – “speculation with other people’s money”). In the present situation in Europe, the proposal of a general Financial Transactions Tax (FTT) has become the most important proposal of this kind.
The struggle over the usefulness of a FTT on the academic level, in the media and in politics, between EU member states as well as within each country, reflects the fundamental differences between the “realistic” and “idealistic” approach to economics. /As the crisis deepens, this struggle will extend to other problem fields like unemployment or the public debt. These struggles are part of the process of destructing the old paradigm and developing a new one (in part by trying new ways in practice as done by the New Deal). Such a process is most typical for the trough phase of the “long cycle”. /
In this essay I shall elaborate upon the most important arguments/weapons of the proponents of and the opponents to a FTT. I’ll try to show that the argument of the proponents are typical for RE reasoning, whereas the arguments of opponents are derived from the “idealistic” economic paradigm. I shall further document how the arguments against a FTT, derived from extremely abstract axioms, legitimate the extremely concrete interests of banks and hedge funds which have been specializing in “finance alchemy” for so long.
Weiter im Text:
http://www.wifo.ac.at/jart/prj3/wifo/resources/person_dokument/person_dokument.jart?publikationsid=47272&mime_type=application/pdf
- [AG-GOuFP] der (vorerst) verlorene Kampf um die Finanztransaktionssteuer, moneymind, 09.08.2014
Archiv bereitgestellt durch MHonArc 2.6.19.